The Economics of Financial Markets
THE ECONOMICS OF FINANCIAL MARKETS
MARKET-MAKERS, BIASED INFORMATION, AND FORECASTS
This tutorial will look at financial markets and
how they actually function.
There are two general theories about how financial
markets work. The first is the Efficient Market Theory, which assumes all
decision-makers are rational – they have access to information, can analyze it,
and make investment decisions. Strangely, a major conclusion is that investors
cannot predict stock price movements, which are random. The second is
Behavioral Finance, which assumes that investors are irrational – they have a
number of biases and are influenced by the markets’ past behavior.
Both theories based on this supposed distinction
that “explain” financial price behavior are irrelevant.
What is left out of theoretical models of financial
markets is how financial markets actually operate. Between buyers (investors)
and sellers (including issuers of new securities), there are market makers like
brokerage firms, managed funds, hedge funds and investment banks. It is in
their interest to get investors to invest in financial assets rather than other
types of assets, to trade often, to buy riskier securities and derivatives. All
these strategies generate more revenue for them.
It is also in their interest to convince investors
to pay large fees for supposedly superior information or analytical skill, that
is, to ignore the Efficient Market Hypothesis. And investors, including large
pension funds, often do.
The primary selling tools are financial
information, analysis of the information, and forecasts. It is the
self-interest of all market-makers to present biased information and optimistic
forecasts. For market-makers, financial information and forecasts are marketing
data.
What is financial information? First, the current
earnings of companies. The problem is politely phrased “quality of earnings.”
Earnings, and earnings per share (EPS), are routinely managed by corporate
accountants to show steady or exponential earnings growth. This increases the
share price as EPS goes up and, if earnings rise by a high or increasing
percent every quarter, by increasing the price/earnings (P/E) ratio of the
stock.
Since top management now receives much of its compensation from stock options and bonuses based on earnings growth, they have a personal reason to see that earnings are managed.
Even a casual reading of the financial press or case studies on corporate finance reveal the numerous ways reported earnings per share can be increased when there is no increase in operating earnings or even a decrease. The simplest way is to increase financial leverage. The current version is to borrow money to finance share buybacks. This increases earnings per share since there are fewer shares outstanding.
For a sample of corporate accounting frauds, see http://www.accounting-degree.org/scandals/. Also
see the entertaining film The Smartest
Guys in the Room.
Then analysts who work for market-makers spin the
earnings. They invent plausible reasons for the steady or accelerating increase
in EPS and P/E ratios. Assuming these reasons will continue if not accelerate,
they make optimistic forecasts of future earnings. Since the stock market is
“forward-looking,” these biased forecasts are important pieces of “information”
that investors use to make decisions. Analysts (and CNBC) become
cheerleaders for the industries and companies they study, especially if they
work for a financial institution that competes for investment banking business.
Often analysts will hype a company that they privately know is a dog.
Analysts overwhelming issue buy or hold
recommendations and very seldom issue sell recommendations.
The worse scenario for an investor is an industry
with new technology. Analysts are free to make whatever predictions they want,
no matter how improbable. A good story sells. In the decades I’ve followed the
stock market, I’ve never heard an analyst tell the simple truth: Almost
all the companies trying to develop a new technology will go bankrupt and it is
impossible to tell which few will be big winners (if any). Think about
the biotech, dotcom and “clean energy” booms. I think it is fair to include the
clever innovations that made the subprime mortgage and derivative boom
possible.
Investors are buying the future. Even stock index
funds, which are weighted averages of the market value of the underlying
stocks, go up mostly because of the more rapid than average increase in the hot
stocks and hot industries.
This game comes to a temporary reversal when there
is an “external shock” such as a recession. The phrase indicates important
events than cannot be forecasted. Then there are the inevitable losses,
“restatement of earnings,” “extraordinary losses” and “write-down of assets.” Hyped new technology companies go bankrupt. Hot stocks
and industries driving the market get clobbered
and indexes go down. Often a lot.
Besides reducing past earnings, companies will also
take a “big bath” write-off of assets and anticipated future expenses. It is
common practice to overestimate future expenses and losses. Then when actual
expenses are incurred, they are smaller than announced and earnings are higher.
This is one reason for the apparent paradox that a company’s stock price often
goes up when the company announces a large loss and a large write-off of
assets.
But memories are short, hope springs eternal and
there is always a new story to tell – a new hot industry, new hot companies,
especially if in a new technology. And the game moves to a different location.
The main point here is that even if investors
“rationally” analyze the biased information and forecasts, their subsequent
behavior will not be any different than “irrational” investors who follow
trends created by the biases and asymmetries of the financial information.
UNDERPRICING RISK AND FAULTY MARKETS
An important part of the information used to make
investment decisions is forecasts. Yet the analytical tools used to forecast,
and also price financial instruments, are defective. They are mostly based on a
normal distribution of price movements and related linear regression models.
Normal distribution models underestimate the probability of a large downward
movement in stock prices. The market has much more risk (volatility) than the
models indicate. Some of the studies and statistics are summarized in Benoit
Mandelbrot, The (Mis)Behavior of Markets. This conclusion has been
popularized in the best-seller, Nassim Taleb’s Fooled by Randomness.
A recent example was the credit default swap
market. The pricing of credit default swaps in the 2000s was based on a
correlation model that assumed away the possibility of defaults! Since AIG
thought there was no risk of actually paying off for defaults, it underpriced
the credit swaps and could not afford to hedge its positions. The resulting
defaults of derivatives and investment companies led to the bankruptcy of the
largest insurance company in the world.
There are some markets that cannot be forecasted.
The bond market is bigger than the stock market. Yet economists cannot forecast
interest rates and thus the movement of bond prices. The mortgage market cannot
be forecasted. The future cash flows of variable rate mortgages are highly
uncertain and fixed rate mortgages can be refinanced. Thus the future cash
flows of mortgage-backed securities cannot be forecasted. Uncertainty is
compounded by leverage in buying mortgage-backed securities (MBSs), the creation of derivatives based on
MBSs, and default risk.
INDEX FUNDS VERSUS MANAGED FUNDS AND PICKING STOCKS: INFORMATION AND IGNORANCE
Financial
markets are information rich. According to economic theory, prices should
reflect this information. The pricing mechanism should be very efficient,
summarizing the analysis of the large amount of data. But most individual
investors and many institutional investors such as pension fund trustees are
totally ignorant of financial markets and incapable of interpreting and
analyzing financial data. What to do?
1)
Pay someone else to analyze data and pick stocks. (Managed funds)
2)
Buy index funds and index ETFs.
An
index fund like the S&P 500 ignores the problem of picking good stocks and
buys the entire stock market. Stocks in the index are weighted by their total
market value (in the jargon, called “market cap,” short for market
capitalization). So the index buys 10 times as much of a stock with a market
cap of $100 billion than another stock with a market cap of $10 billion. The
index has to adjust the weights as the relative market caps change.
Indexes
tend to be dominated by very large companies and rapidly growing technology
companies with high and rising P/E ratios. Before the 2008-2009 crash, indexes
were dominated by financial companies. Six of the top ten market cap companies
in the S&P 500 are tech companies. Currently (2018), the eight companies in
the world with the highest market cap are all information technology companies.
“Buying
the market” (index funds) rather than individual stocks is a strategy for
totally ignorant investors. Much of the increase in money going into the stock
market after the 2008-2009 crash has gone into index funds and index ETFs. All
that investors have to assume (believe) is that the real economy will grow,
total profits and earnings per share (EPS) will thus increase, and that most if
not all stock prices will rise as a consequence. Investors can ignore the
competitive strategies and financial performance of individual companies,
industry analysis, monetary and fiscal policies, and global and macroeconomic
trends.
And
total ignorance works. A great deal of statistical evidence indicates that
index funds outperform over 90% of managed funds over long periods of time.
They also have lower costs – no expensive analysis costs. Managed fund managers
also tend to take greater risks and create leverage (invest with borrowed funds
in additional to investors’ money) to offset higher costs and achieve higher
rates of return than index funds. Because of greater leverage, greater risk,
and high costs, managed funds tend to do poorly in stock market downturns. Many
“blow up” (go out of business).
Index
funds work because in the long run the economy does grow, total profits of
public companies rise, and most stock prices go up. As more money goes into
index funds, the funds must buy more of all of the stocks in the fund.
The whole market goes up and the index funds prosper.
All
of this also benefits managed funds. Experienced fund managers with access to
all past and current financial and economic data, data and trend analysis
programs, and proprietary models should be able to outperform the market in
such an environment. But they do not. Why?
They
are making decisions based on biased and misleading information.
There
is a problem of too much information that is hard to analyze. For example, many
companies no longer release an annual report. Instead, they send their
stockholders (and analysts) their 10-k, which is the annual report they have to
file with the government’s Securities and Exchange Commission (the SEC). These
are incredibly detailed reports with small type that go on typically for
100-150 pages. Most of the content is unimportant or irrelevant. (This is the
mushroom effect. How do you raise mushrooms?
Keep them in the dark and pile manure on them.)
They
tend to buy companies with rapidly rising sales and profits. These companies
also have high and rising P/E ratios during the innovative, rapid growth phase,
increasing the rise in the stock price. As these innovative companies mature,
their growth slows down. Profit growth also slows down or stops. P/E ratios
fall. The result is a drop in their stock price, often large, followed by
mediocre stock performance. Many of these companies are attacked by smaller
companies developing or using newer technology.
Companies like IBM, Microsoft, Intel, and Oracle
were innovative growth companies, are now large and profitable, but have been lousy
stock investments for a long time. The large percentage increase in their stock
prices in 2017 and early 2018 looks similar to the large runup in their prices
in 1999, just before the dotcom market crash of 2000-2002.
Professional
investors cannot predict “phase transitions” in industry technology or
organization, or in the underlying economy. Just as it is difficult to predict
the winners developing a new technology, it is difficult to predict the losers
they will replace. It is the winners, not the losers, that make it into the
indexes.
Managed
funds do a lot of trading – buying and selling stocks in their portfolio. They
try to time their trades with major moves in the stock market. This is
difficult to do. Very few investment professionals ever predict market
downturns.
Some
managed funds buy a subset of large, mature companies. A diversified portfolio
of about 30 stocks reduces risk almost as much as a total market index. Their
economic performance as a group will be about the same as the large, mature
companies in the index funds. With about the same sales and profit growth over
time, the subsets in the managed funds should have long-term stock price
increases about the same as the market. But at a higher cost.
On
average, about 60-70% of an individual stock’s price movement will be
correlated to the price movement of the whole market. So, much of the movement
of stocks in a managed funds will move with the market, especially a managed
fund dominated by large companies with large market capitalization.
Some
large cap companies are so diversified that they are a diversified portfolio in
themselves. Johnson & Johnson could represent much of the pharmaceutical
and health care industry. Parker Hannifin could be a proxy for investing in
cyclical industrial companies. Companies like Google and Celgene buy or invest
in new and small technology companies in their industries, almost like a
venture capital company. Many large companies not only have a diversified
business but are also multinational corporations, a proxy for investing outside
the United States.
Some
managed funds concentrate on innovative companies. The problem is that many new
tech and startup companies fail; their stock prices will go to zero. Many did
in the 2000-2002 dotcom market downturn. They took a lot of managed funds down
with them.
As
discussed throughout these tutorials, an important factor for the success of a
startup is the drive, determination, focus, and strategy of the
founders/entrepreneurs. It is hard for an outsider like an investment manager
to evaluate the intelligence, dedication, and personality of the founders.
Outside
analysts and investors do not have the key information they need to evaluate a
company – the internal detailed proprietary knowledge responsible for the
competitive advantage causing sales and profit growth.
Most
stocks, including those of the large, mature companies that tend to dominate
index funds tend to go up and down (are correlated) with the overall market.
There may be individual exceptions because of company-specific events but as a
group they heavily influence (account for) overall stock market changes. There
is no need to try to pick individual stocks among this group.
Often,
one sector drives the market – IT and Internet stocks in the 1990s, finance in
the 2000s, and technology in the 2010s. It is hard to pick winners early and
the timing of the downturn is also unpredictable. Index funds ride through the
downturn and are there for the next upturn fueled by innovative companies in
new sectors and industries.
There
are internal dynamics of the stock market. Companies increase dividends, buy
back their stock, and do mergers and acquisitions. All these moves can increase
the price of an individual stock; collectively, they increase the value of the
entire stock market. Index funds automatically benefit. Managed funds often do
not.
Picking
stocks to outperform the market critically depends on predicting growth rates
in expected EPS for years into the future. Any forecast will be highly
uncertain and subject to large errors.
In
conclusion, the stock market is not a random walk (impossible to forecast) or
the result of irrational, emotional behavior by investors and money managers.
Professional money managers seldom “beat the market” because of uncertain forecasts,
the domination of mature companies, the difficulty of outsiders to pick
innovative winners, and incomplete and misleading data.
I
recommend reading Burton Malkiel, A
Random Walk Down Wall Street. Revised and Updated Edition, 2007. Professor
Malkiel was associated with Vanguard for a long time. Earlier editions of this
book were an argument for the index fund approach to investing made popular by
Vanguard. This edition gives a more balanced approach than earlier editions.
INSIDER INFORMATION: PROFITING FROM ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION
Financial markets are rife with insider
information. Inside information is a classic example of asymmetrical
information, where insiders can profit at the benefit of investors not yet
knowing the information. Sometimes insiders use their information and position
to manipulate prices, such as the massive LIBOR price-fixing scandal.
Many foreign markets are insider markets, where
locals can conspire to manipulate and fix prices, especially at the expense of
foreign investors. This is similar to what U.S. markets were like before the
reforms of the 1930s.
FINANCIAL MARKETS AND MORAL HAZARD
Conservatives argue that deregulation of financial
markets leads to innovation and more efficient markets. The first part is true;
many new financial instruments and new types of financial companies have been
created. The implication of the second part is that because of more competition
prices in financial markets quickly adjust to something approaching
“fundamental value” or, in economic jargon, equilibrium. The basic problem is
that the first effect works against the second effect.
The problem is moral hazard, an idea that says that
individuals like managers and owners of financial institutions will take more
risk if someone else (the U.S. government and taxpayers) pays the price of
failure.
This happened in the savings and loan crisis of the
late 1980s. The industry was deregulated so that S&L managers could make
riskier loans at higher interest rates but deposits were still federally
insured. So the more aggressive banks offered higher interest rates on
deposits, took in a lot of money, and made a lot of high-risk bets, including
illegal loans to insiders. They lost. Half of the S&Ls went bankrupt and it
cost U.S. taxpayers over $130 billion in losses on bad loans.
Deposit insurance is one source of moral hazard.
Another is that the two largest players in the mortgage market, Fannie Mae and
Freddie Mac, had the implicit guarantee of the government. A third source is
the “too big to fail” doctrine, already invoked in a big bank rescue in the
1980s. Combined with that is the idea of “systemic risk,” which implies that if
a financial institution failed, even if it wasn’t a bank or “too big to fail,”
it might set off a chain reaction that would threaten the collapse of the
entire financial system. This is what happened with the failure of Long-Term
Capital Management in 1998.
EXTREME RISK AND TOO BIG TO FAIL: LONG-TERM CAPITAL MANAGEMENT (LTCM)
In the 1990s, the company with the most
sophisticated models and trading strategies was Long-Term Capital Management.
Its partners included the former head of bond trading at Solomon and two Nobel
Prize winners for their work in financial models (Myron Scholes and Robert
Merton). Its strategy was based on reversion to the mean of the difference in
the prices of a large number of supposedly unrelated financial instruments,
another correlation model. But in the global financial crisis environment of
1998, the difference in prices moved in the opposite direction of historical
behavior partly because of a “run to safety” in buying U.S. Treasuries. Spreads
between Treasuries and other instruments increased instead of the expected
decrease. This, plus enormous leverage based on underestimating risk, led to a
massive bankruptcy. Only a huge infusion of capital from other firms, made
under pressure from the Fed, averted a financial crisis.
LTCM was a hedge fund so the government had no
legal obligation to intervene. It also wasn’t that large in terms of capital
invested. But it was very highly leveraged, meaning it had borrowed a huge
amount of money (about 30 times its invested capital) and had over $100 billion
of assets and liabilities on its balance sheet. If it failed, its lenders and
counterparties to financial contracts would take a huge hit; it was believed
that some credit markets might even freeze up (become illiquid). The Fed
decided that this was too big a risk to take and forced nine major banks to
chip in over $3 billion to carry the assets. LTCM was liquidated and its
positions were eventually sold. But it established a precedent that a threat to
financial markets, not necessarily the size of the company or the legal
obligation of the government, might be a reason for the government to bailout a
company. And the threat to financial markets was rapidly increasing as all
large financial institutions increased their leverage in the 1990s and 2000s,
many to the 30-1 ratio of LTCM. They were using borrowed funds to buy and trade
inherently risky mortgage-based bonds and derivatives.
BIASED INFORMATION, FRAUD, EXTREME RISK, AND TOO BIG
TO FAIL: THE SUBPRIME MORTGAGE MARKET CRASH OF
2007-2009
After the Dotcom market bust of 2000-2002, the
market continued upward, fueled by tremendous gains in the financial markets.
Financial firms had found a great new business – securitizing mortgages and
other debt instruments and selling bonds and other derivatives based on the
cash flow of the underlying assets. At the foundation of this was a huge
increase in subprime mortgages and mortgage refinancing. Many of the subprime
mortgages were blatantly fraudulent or certain to go into default. But banks
and other financial institutions were able to sell pyramids of derivatives many
times greater, and more profitable, than the original issuance of mortgages.
These markets were totally unregulated. (To understand how all this happened,
see the movie The Big Short and read Explaining
Derivatives – An Analogy after this essay.)
The subprime mortgage business was a con game from
the start. Mortgage brokers and loan officers at sketchy banks used deceptive
and often fraudulent methods to originate subprime loans. Mortgage and
mortgage-baked securities (MBSs) risk analysts at some banks and investment
banks, the credit rating agencies, and Fannie Mae knew that there would be a
high rate of default after the low “teaser” rates ran out. In loftier language,
Alan Greenspan warned in 1994 that there was a good possibility of a housing
bubble and massive defaults of mortgages.
The problem was how to sell these “junk” mortgages.
In a rational market, investors in subprime mortgages and their MBSs should
have received high rates of return to balance the high risks of default. Not to
be. If banks kept the mortgages, they could be financed by low-cost short-term
borrowing. Why low cost? Because throughout most of the 2000s, the Fed kept short-term
interest rates low. The prime rate was below 2% for three years.
But banks sold most of subprime mortgages to other
financial institutions that would securitize the mortgages into bonds backed by
the monthly payments of the mortgage holders. The bonds should have paid a high
rate of return. But they didn’t. The reason was that these mortgages and their
derivatives were laundered. The financial industry, with the connivance of
credit rating agencies that were paid by the banks, turned bundles of high-risk
mortgages into bundles of investment-grade (low-risk) bonds. Then the riskier
parts of these bundles were turned into new derivatives that were also rated as
investment grade. By labeling these securities as investment grade, this
greatly increased the pool of potential institutional buyers such as pension
funds. Mortgage origination fees, underwriting fees, selling fees and trading
commissions were enormous.
But who bought these instruments? At the height of
the subprime boom, large purchasers were Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. In the
past, both companies would have automatically rejected subprime mortgages. They
didn’t even have models to evaluate these types of mortgages. As companies with
de facto government guarantees, they were obligated to only buy and securitize
high quality, low-risk mortgages. But under political and industry pressure,
and loss of market share, they became major buyers of subprimes and sold
mortgage-backed bonds at rates slightly higher than U.S. government bonds.
Massive defaults led to the bankruptcy of both companies, which were taken over
by the federal government. For political reasons, most of the losses were not
borne by the bondholders such as the Chinese government but by U.S. taxpayers.
So the consequence of deregulation was not
diversifying risk and self-equilibrating financial markets but accelerating
systemic risk underwritten by moral hazard. How could it be otherwise? Selling
greater volumes of increasingly riskier assets meant huge increases in salaries
and bonuses. What did mortgage originators and managers of banks, investment
banks and hedge funds care if they were creating higher levels of risk that
could bring down their companies or the entire financial system? Increased
leverage meant increased profits and increased bonuses. Fraud was rampant.
Regulators were either clueless (SEC) or ignored their feelings that a crash
was coming (Greenspan). Most deals were private so that even the hope of “free
market discipline” was missing. Best of all, there were huge pools of funds run
by unsophisticated trustees (asymmetric information) to finance the whole
thing. Wall Street’s attitude was nicely summarized in a line from the movie The Magnificent Seven, “If God didn’t
want them sheared, He wouldn’t have made them sheep.”
Will it happen again? Of course. The financial
reform bill is a joke, nothing more than a political CYA crafted by the same
politicians that helped create the mess. But the Congressional hearings were
good theater as every member of Congress repeated a variation of the cynical
line from the movie Casablanca, “I am
shocked, shocked, to find out that gambling is going on in here!”
As part of its attempt to save the financial
industry from imploding, the government brokered a number of “shotgun” mergers
between large financial institutions. A small number of banks are now much
larger than before the bailouts. They really are “too big to fail.” They are
more dominant, gaining market share. They are also closely tied to the large
hedge funds and private equity firms, which gives these private, unregulated
companies some government protection. And, in a delicious irony, Goldman Sachs,
a major private derivatives and trading investment bank, has applied to become
a commercial bank so that FDIC can protect some of their creditors. The idea
that American taxpayers are providing insurance to Goldman Sachs’ creditors,
which include hedge funds, is moral hazard with a vengeance.
Government bailouts went way beyond the usual
targets, to include insurance companies, General Motors’ and Chrysler’s
financial arms, and GE Capital. There is delicious irony in the bailout of GE
Capital. GE Capital is part of General Electric (GE), one of the largest
corporations in the world. For many years, GE has paid no U.S. corporate income
tax.
A last, major example of moral hazard. Public and private pension funds have made risky investments
and lost. So what? The public pension funds must
have a certain level of assets in the future. So future taxpayers will pay more
in taxes and receive fewer services. And $60 billion of unfunded liabilities in
private pension funds are guaranteed by the government.
Large financial firms can expect public bailouts
and subsidies when they “blow-up” but investors cannot. So financial firms can
take excessive risks with investors’ money to earn large fees. It is only when
they start to believe their own propaganda that the financial instruments they
sell are really not as risky as they are, and begin holding the securities in
their own portfolios, that financial institutions risk bankruptcy.
What this means is that in the future just about any company remotely related to finance can expect a bailout. There are no market restraints on risk left. The U.S. government is now underwriting the entire financial industry, no matter how reckless. And every risk-taking gunslinger in the future knows it.
CONCLUSIONS
Analytical tools and
analysts are biased producing biased information
and forecasts.
Statistical models underestimate risk. Risk is
underpriced and uncertainty cannot be modeled. Combined with the upward bias in
public information, this creates higher percent growth of financial prices in
“normal” times followed by periodic “blow-ups” in financial markets.
Moral hazard allows investment managers
to take great risks since they know that the government or taxpayers will
underwrite large losses.
The information and knowledge that most professionals possess does not give them an advantage over the total ignorance of investing in passive index funds. They cannot "beat the market."
The information and knowledge that most professionals possess does not give them an advantage over the total ignorance of investing in passive index funds. They cannot "beat the market."
===============================================
EXPLAINING DERIVATIVES – AN ANALOGY
You go around to farmers with cows. You buy all the
cows and pay the farmers a small fee to milk the cows and sell the milk. You
pay for the cows with ass(et)-backed securities called MBSs (Milked Bovine
Securities) that you tell investors are udderly safe. But some of the cows
don't give enough milk (cow flow problem) or give no milk at all. You take some
of the asset-backed securities, say they're backed by the subprime cows, and
use them as collateral to sell another set of securities called CMOs (Cow Milk
Obligations). Then you buy CDSs (Cow Dried-up Swaps) from AIG (Angus Insurance
Company) to insure the CMOs when the cows stopped giving milk. If you work it
right, you collect more on the CDSs than you pay out to retire the CMOs. The
money you get from selling the dead cows go to pay the CLOs (cow leather
obligations).
You could also sell CDOs (cow dung obligations)
that depend on how much cow dung is produced. This is a typical Wall Street
product - turning shit into gold.
Comments
Post a Comment